America’s dark imperial legacy: It goes much deeper than George W. Bush
While our 43rd president rightly takes blame for his disastrous failed wars, there’s much more blame to go around
Robert W. McChesney11.16.2014•3:59 AM •61 Comments
The United States unique today among major states
in the degree of its reliance on military spending and its determination
to stand astride the world, militarily as well as economically. No
other country in the post–Second World War world has been so globally
destructive or inflicted so many war fatalities. Since 2001,
acknowledged U.S. national defense spending has increased by almost 60
percent in real dollar terms to a level in 2007 of $553 billion. This is
higher than at any point since the Second World War (though lower than
previous decades as a percentage of GDP). Based on such official
figures, the United States is reported by the Stockholm International
Peace Research Institute (SIPRI) as accounting for 45 percent of world
military expenditures. Yet, so gargantuan and labyrinthine are U.S.
military expenditures that their true magnitude reached $1 trillion in
2007.
Externally, these are necessary expenditures of
world empire. Internally, they represent, as Michal Kalecki was the
first to suggest, an imperial triangle of state-financed military
production, media propaganda, and real/imagined economic-employment
effects that has become a deeply entrenched and self-perpetuating
feature of the U.S. social order.
Many analysts today view the present growth of U.S.
militarism and imperialism as largely divorced from the earlier Cold
War history of the United States, which was commonly seen as a response
to the threat represented by the Soviet Union. Placed against this
backdrop the current turn to war and war preparation appears to numerous
commentators to lack a distinct target, despite concerns about global
terrorism, and to be mainly the product of irrational hubris on the part
of U.S. leaders. Even as insightful a left historian as Eric Hobsbawm
has recently adopted this general perspective. Thus in his 2008 book On
Empire Hobsbawm writes:
Frankly, I can’t make sense of what has happened in the United States since 9/11 that enabled a group of political crazies to realize long-held plans for an unaccompanied solo performance of world supremacy. . . . Today a radical right-wing regime seeks to mobilize “true Americans” against some evil outside force and against a world that does not recognize the uniqueness, the superiority, the manifest destiny of America. . . . In effect, the most obvious danger of war today arises from the global ambitions of an uncontrollable and apparently irrational government in Washington. . . . To give America the best chance of learning to return from megalomania to rational foreign policy is the most immediate and urgent task of international politics.
Such a view, which sees the United States as under
the influence of a new irrationalism introduced by George W. Bush and a
cabal of neoconservative “political crazies,” and consequently calls
for a return from “megalomania to rational foreign policy,” downplays
the larger historical and structural forces at work that connect the
Cold War and post–Cold War imperial eras. In contrast, a more realistic
perspective, I believe, can be obtained by looking at the origins of the
U.S. “military ascendancy” (as C. Wright Mills termed it) in the early
Cold War years and the centrality this has assumed in the constitution
of the U.S. empire and economy up to the present.
The Permanent War Economy and Military Keynesianism
In January 1944 Charles E. Wilson, president of
General Electric and executive vice chairman of the War Production
Board, delivered a speech to the Army Ordnance Association advocating a
permanent war economy. According to the plan Wilson proposed on that
occasion, every major corporation should have a “liaison” representative
with the military, who would be given a commission as a colonel in the
Reserve. This would form the basis of a program, to be initiated by the
president as commander-in-chief in cooperation with the War and Navy
departments, designed to bind corporations and the military together
into a single unified armed forces–industrial complex. “What is more
natural and logical,” he asked, “than that we should henceforth mount
our national policy upon the solid fact of an industrial capacity for
war, and a research capacity for war that is already ‘in being’? It
seems to me anything less is foolhardy.” Wilson went on to indicate that
in this plan the part to be played by Congress was restricted to voting
for the needed funds. Further, it was essential that industry be
allowed to play its central role in this new warfare state without being
hindered politically “or thrown to the fanatical isolationist fringe
[and] tagged with a ‘merchants-of-death’ label.”
In calling even before the Second World War had
come to a close for a “continuing program of industrial preparedness”
for war, Charles E. Wilson (sometimes referred to as “General Electric
Wilson” to distinguish him from “General Motors Wilson”—Charles Erwin
Wilson, president of General Motors and Eisenhower’s secretary of
defense) was articulating a view that was to characterize the U.S.
oligarchy as a whole during the years immediately following the Second
World War. In earlier eras it had been assumed that there was an
economic “guns and butter” trade-off, and that military spending had to
occur at the expense of other sectors of the economy. However, one of
the lessons of the economic expansion in Nazi Germany, followed by the
experience of the United States itself in arming for the Second World
War, was that big increases in military spending could act as huge
stimulants to the economy. In just six years under the influence of the
Second World War, the U.S. economy expanded by 70 percent, finally
recovering from the Great Depression. The early Cold War era thus saw
the emergence of what later came to be known as “military Keynesianism”:
the view that by promoting effective demand and supporting monopoly
profits military spending could help place a floor under U.S.
capitalism.
John Maynard Keynes, in his landmark General
Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, published in 1936, in the
midst of the Depression, argued that the answer to economic stagnation
was to promote effective demand through government spending. The
bastardized Keynesianism that came to be known as “military
Keynesianism” was the view that this was best effected with the least
negative consequences for big business by focusing on military spending.
As Joan Robinson, one of Keynes’s younger colleagues, critically
explained in her iconoclastic lecture, “The Second Crisis of Economic
Theory,” before the American Economic Association on December 27, 1971:
The most convenient thing for a government to spend on is armaments. The military-industrial complex [thus] took charge. I do not think it plausible to suppose that the Cold War and several hot wars were invented just to solve the employment problem. But certainly they have had that effect. The system had the support not only of the corporations who make profits under it and the workers who got jobs, but also of the economists who advocated government loan-expenditure as a prophylactic against stagnation. Whatever were the deeper forces leading to the hypertrophy of military power after the world war was over, certainly they could not have had such free play if the doctrine of sound finance had still been respected. It was the so-called Keynesians who persuaded successive Presidents that there is no harm in a budget deficit and left the military-industrial complex to take advantage of it. So it has come about that Keynes’ pleasant daydream was turned into a nightmare of terror.
The first to theorize this tendency toward
military Keynesianism under monopoly capitalism was the Polish economist
Michal Kalecki (most famous, as Robinson pointed out in the
above-mentioned lecture, for having discovered the essentials of
Keynes’s General Theory before Keynes himself). In a 1943 essay on “The
Political Aspects of Full Employment” and in subsequent essays, Kalecki
argued that monopoly capital had a deep aversion to increased civilian
government spending due to its intrusion on the commodity market and the
sphere of private profit, but that this did not apply in the same way
to military spending, which was seen by the vested interests as adding
to, rather than crowding out, profits. If absorption of the massive
economic surplus of large corporate capital through increased government
spending was the key to accumulation in post–Second World War U.S.
capitalism, this was dependent principally on military expenditures, or
what Kalecki in 1956 labeled “the armament-imperialist complex.” This
resulted in a “high degree of utilization” of productive capacity and
“counteracted the disrupting influence of the increase in the relative
share of accumulation of big business in the national product.”
For Kalecki this new military-supported regime of
accumulation that came to characterize U.S. monopoly capital by the
mid-1950s established a strong political-economic foundation for its own
rule “based on the following [imperial] triangle”:
- Imperialism contributes to a relatively high level of employment through expenditures on armaments and ancillary purposes and through the maintenance of a large body of armed forces and government employees.
- The mass communications media, working under the auspices of the ruling class, emits propaganda aimed at securing the support of the population for this armament-imperialist setup.
- The high level of employment and the standard of living increased considerably as compared with before the war (as a result of the rise in the productivity of labor), and this facilitated the absorption of this propaganda to the broad masses of the population.
Mass communication occupied a central place in
this imperial triangle. An essential part of Kalecki’s argument was that
“the mass communication media, such as the daily press, radio, and
television in the United States, are largely under the control of the
ruling class.” As none other than Charles E. (General Electric) Wilson,
then defense mobilization director, put it in a speech to the American
Newspaper Publishers Association on April 26, 1951, the job of the media
was to bring “public opinion, as marshaled by the press” to the support of the permanent war effort (italics added).
The result by the mid-1950s was a fairly stable
militarized economy, in which intertwined imperial, political-economic,
and communication factors all served to reinforce the new
military-imperial order.
Kalecki observed that U.S. trade unions were “part
and parcel of the armament-imperialist setup. Workers in the United
States are not duller and trade union leaders are not more reactionary
‘by nature’ than in other capitalist countries. Rather, the political
situation in the United States is simply, in accordance with the
precepts of historical materialism, the unavoidable consequence of
economic developments and of characteristics of the superstructure of
monopoly capitalism in its advanced stage.” All of this pointed to what
Harry Magdoff was to call the essential “one-ness of national security
and business interests” that came to characterize the U.S. political
economy and empire.
Many of Kalecki’s ideas were developed further by
Paul Baran and Paul Sweezy in 1966 in Monopoly Capital. Baran and Sweezy
argued there were at least five political-economic-imperial ends
propelling the U.S. oligarchy in the 1950s and ’60s toward the creation
of a massive military establishment: (1) defending U.S. global hegemony
and the empire of capital against external threats in the form of a wave
of revolutions erupting throughout the world, simplistically viewed in
terms of a monolithic Communist threat centered in the Soviet Union; (2)
creating an internationally “secure” platform for U.S. corporations to
expand and monopolize economic opportunities abroad; (3) forming a
government-sponsored research and development sector that would be
dominated by big business; (4) generating a more complacent population
at home, made less recalcitrant under the nationalistic influence of
perpetual war and war preparation; and (5) soaking up the nation’s vast
surplus productive capacity, thus helping to stave off economic
stagnation, through the promotion of high-profit, low-risk (to business)
military spending. The combined result of such
political-economic-imperial factors was the creation of the largest,
most deeply entrenched and persistent “peacetime” war machine that the
world had ever seen.
Like Kalecki, Baran and Sweezy argued that the
U.S. oligarchy kept a “tight rein on civilian [government] spending,”
which, they suggested, “had about reached its outer limits” as a
percentage of national income “by 1939,” but was nonetheless
“open-handed with the military.” Government pump-priming operations
therefore occurred largely through spending on wars and war preparations
in the service of empire. The Pentagon naturally made sure that bases
and armaments industries were spread around the United States and that
numerous corporations profited from military spending, thus maximizing
congressional support due to the effects on states and districts.
For members of the U.S. oligarchy and their
hangers-on, the virtuous circle of mutually reinforcing military
spending and economic growth represented by military Keynesianism was
something to be celebrated rather than held up to criticism. Harvard
economist Sumner Slichter explained to a banker’s convention in October
1949 that as long as Cold War spending persisted, a severe economic
depression was “difficult to conceive.” The Cold War “increases the
demand for goods, helps sustain a high level of employment, accelerates
technological progress and thus helps the country to raise its standard
of living. . . . So we may thank the Russians for helping make
capitalism in the United States work better than ever.”
Similarly, U.S. News and World Report told its readers on May 14, 1950 (a month before the outbreak of the Korean War):
Government planners figure they have found the magic formula for almost endless good times. They are now beginning to wonder if there may not be something to perpetual motion after all. Cold war is the catalyst. Cold war is an automatic pump primer. Turn a spigot, and the public clamors for more arms spending. Turn another, the clamor ceases. Truman confidence, cockiness, is based on this “Truman formula.” Truman era of good times, President is told, can run much beyond 1952. Cold war demands, if fully exploited, are almost limitless.
In the same vein, U.S. News and World Report was
to declare in 1954: “What H-bomb means to business. A long period . . .
of big orders. In the years ahead, the effects of the new bomb will keep
on increasing. As one appraiser puts it: ‘The H-bomb has blown
Depression-thinking out the window.’” (In 1959 David Lawrence, editor of
U.S. News and World Report, indicated that he viewed with equanimity
the suggestion that the United States “might conceivably strike first in
what has become known as ‘preemptive’ rather than ‘preventive’ war.”)
Henry Luce, the media mogul at the head of the
Time-Life empire, who coined the term “the American Century,” observed
in November 1957 in Fortune that the United States “can stand the load
of any defense effort required to hold the power of Soviet Russia in
check. It cannot, however, indefinitely stand the erosion of creeping
socialism and the ceaseless extension of government activities into
additional economic fields” beyond the military. This was directly in
line with Kalecki’s and Baran and Sweezy’s contention that the system
was tight-fisted where civilian spending was concerned and open-handed
with the military.
Remarking on the success of military Keynesianism
in promoting economic prosperity, the influential Harvard economist
Seymour Harris wrote in the New York Times Magazine in 1959: “If we
treat the years from 1941 to the present as a whole, we find again that a
period of record prosperity coincided with a period of heavy military
outlay. . . . About one dollar out of seven went for war and preparation
for war, and this expenditure was undoubtedly a stimulus to the
economy.”
A military Keynesian view was close to the heart
of the major U.S. planning document of the Cold War. It was called
NSC-68, and it was issued in April 1950 shortly before the Korean War by
the U.S. National Security Council and signed by President Truman in
September 1950 (but not declassified until 1975). Drafted by Paul Nitze,
then head of the policy review group in the State Department, NSC-68
intended to construct a rollback strategy against the Soviet Union. It
called for a vast increase in military spending above its already high
levels and considered the possibility that “in an emergency the United
States could devote upward of 50 percent of its gross national product”
to the military effort as in the Second World War. “From the point of
view of the economy as a whole,” NSC-68 declared,
the program [of military expansion] might not result in a real decrease in the standard of living, for the economic effects of the program might be to increase the gross national product by more than the amount being absorbed for additional military and foreign assistance purposes. One of the most significant lessons of our World War II experience was that the American economy, when it operates at a level approaching full efficiency [full capacity], can provide enormous resources for purposes other than civilian consumption while simultaneously providing a high standard of living. After allowing for price changes, personal consumption expenditures rose by almost one-fifth between 1939 and 1944, even though the economy had in the meantime increased the amount of resources going into Government use by $60–$65 billion (in 1939 prices).
U.S.
militarism was therefore motivated first and foremost by a global
geopolitical struggle, but was at the same time seen as essentially
costless (even beneficial) to the U.S. economy, which could have more
guns and more butter too. It was thus viewed as a win-win solution for
the U.S. empire and economy.
By the time that President Eisenhower (who played a
role in this military expansion) raised concerns about what he dubbed
the “military-industrial complex” in his farewell address of January 17,
1961, it was already so firmly established as to constitute the
permanent war economy envisioned by Charles E. Wilson. As Eisenhower’s
secretary of defense, Charles Erwin Wilson—best known for having created
a major flap by saying that “what is good for General Motors is good
for the country”—observed in 1957, the military setup was then so built
into the economy as to make it virtually irreversible. “So many
Americans,” he noted, “are getting a vested interest in it: Properties,
business, jobs, employment, votes, opportunities for promotion and
advancement, bigger salaries for scientists and all that. . . . If you
try to change suddenly you get into trouble. . . . If you shut the whole
business off now, you will have the state of California in trouble
because such a big percentage of the aircraft industry is in
California.”
Hence, the concern that Eisenhower voiced in his
farewell address about a “permanent armaments industry of vast
proportions” and that “we annually spend on military security alone more
than the net income of all United States corporations” was a belated
recognition of what had already become an established fact. The need for
the gargantuan military-industrial complex that the United States
developed in these years was not so much for purposes of economic
expansion directly (though military Keynesianism pointed to its
stimulating effects) but due to the reality, as Baran and Sweezy
emphasized, that the capitalist world order and U.S. hegemony could only
be maintained “a while longer,” in the face of rising insurgencies
throughout the world, through “increasingly direct and massive
intervention by American armed forces.” This entire built-in military
system could not be relinquished without relinquishing empire. And so
from the early Cold War years to today, the United States has flexed its
military power—either directly, resulting in millions of deaths
(counting those who died in the Korean War, the Vietnam War, the Gulf
War, the Kosovo war, the Afghanistan and Iraq wars, as well as dozens of
lesser conflicts), or indirectly, as a means to intimidate.
The most important left analysts of these
developments in the 1950s and ’60s, Kalecki, Baran, Sweezy, and Magdoff,
insisted— going against the dominant U.S. Cold War ideology—that the
cause of U.S. military spending was capitalist empire, rather than the
need to contain the Soviet threat. The benefits of military spending to
monopoly capital, moreover, guaranteed its continuation, barring a major
social upheaval. The decade and a half since the fall of the Soviet
Union has confirmed the accuracy of this assessment. The euphoria of the
“peace dividend” following the end of the Cold War evaporated almost
immediately in the face of new imperial requirements. This was a moment
of truth for U.S. capitalism, demonstrating how deeply entrenched were
its military-imperial interests. By the end of the 1990s U.S. military
spending, which had been falling, was on its way up again.
Today, in what has been called a “unipolar world,”
U.S. military spending for purposes of empire is rapidly expanding—to
the point that it rivals the entire rest of the world put together. When
it is recognized that most of the other top ten military-spending
nations are U.S. allies or junior partners, it makes the U.S. military
ascendancy even more imposing. Only the reality of global empire (and
the effects of this on the internal body politic) can explain such an
overwhelming destructive power. As Atlantic correspondent Robert Kaplan
proudly proclaimed in 2005: “By the turn of the twenty-first century the
United States military had already appropriated the entire earth, and
was ready to flood the most obscure areas of it with troops at a
moment’s notice."
Excerpted from “Blowing the Roof off the Twenty-First Century: Media, Politics, and the Struggle for Post-Capitalist Democracy” by
Robert W. McChesney. Copyright © 2014 by Robert W. McChesney. Reprinted
by arrangement with Monthly Review Press. All rights reserved.
No comments:
Post a Comment